“Everybody wants to go to heaven, but no one wants to die to get there”

If you ever want to make a good case against communism to a worker, tell her that communists want the following things:

  • Everyone is unemployed
  • No one has any income
  • Democracy no longer exists
  • No one can own anything

The paradox of communism is that it appears to involve conditions that are absolutely unacceptable to any rational person. Who in their right mind wants to give up having a job that pays a decent wage, the right to vote and control over means of production? And why would anyone who claims to fight for social emancipation stand for these sorts of things.

NEW_EARTH_9Yes, you can try to clean this shit up by saying, “Oh, I don’t mean everyone is unemployed; what I meant is no more wage labor”, but people are not dumb. They know that when you write  “No more wage labor”, what you really mean is  “100% unemployment.” They know that communist want to put everyone out of a job — which, if you communists ever succeed, will kill the economy and, in most scenarios they can imagine, plunge us all into poverty.

And don’t say you don’t want this, because communists don’t think people should even be paid for their labor power.

So tell me this: How are people supposed to pay their bills if they don’t get paid for their labor power? Do you just think we can all just stop paying our bills?  And then what? Who will build the roads? Who will grow the food? What if I get sick and need medical attention? Who will educate my kids?

Confronted by these sorts of questions, most communists I have read or talked to immediately begin trying to show how their imagined communist utopia will work — they build imaginary systems, or cite limited experiments, like these ideas mentioned by Alan Nasser in a recent article:

“We have real-world examples that can serve as a starting point for a working model of a democratic socialist economy. Mondragon leaps to mind. For about twenty-five years Yugoslavia under Tito had an economy in which workers leased productive facilities fron government, organized production themselves and determined the distribution of the firm’s revenues between wages and reinvestment in the firm. In After Capitalism (Rowman and Littlefield, 2011), David Schweickart offers a refined and realistic model of what a practicable democratic socialist economy would look like, based in part on the Yugoslav experiment. Gar Alperovitz (What Then Must We Do?, Chelsea Green, 2013) and Michael Albert (Parecon: Life After Capitalism, Verso, 2003) have also contributed to the discussion. There’s plenty of grist for our mill.”

The question raised by Nasser’s examples are two-fold: First, if Yugoslavia was so successful, where is it today? Second, why, in all of examples cited, do we never clearly see a path to the end of class, labor, property and the state? Because they can never move beyond certain definite limits, these systems always collapse into some new state, some new method of coercing labor, and some new form of property.

The paradox of communism

This is what I call the paradox of communism: Everything communists stand for appears in this society as a catastrophe to existing society. This paradox is not simply a product of the lack of imagination of folks in present society. To go from a situation where everyone has to sell their labor power to communism under the premises of present society implies an ever bigger shitload of people can’t find work. Communism may be the end of wage labor, but getting to the end of wage labor implies ever increasing unemployment, competition to sell labor power and social disruption. And if people can’t find work, they will turn to people who promise to create work, not those who argue we can live without it.

What distinguishes communism from politics is not the realization that the end of wage labor is a good — which it never appears to be empirically — but that it is inevitable. So 100% unemployment may not figure as a benefit for the working class, but it is the inevitable result of processes taking place beneath present society.

It cannot be avoided.

This is what Ben Noys calls the “radical or quasi-Marxist ‘cunning of reason'” — the idea that in the capitalistic mode of production unemployment is the most likely path to communism. Noys’ argument is simply the academic version of the reaction any worker would have if you told them communism aims to get rid of their job. And Noys’ reaction to this process is exactly what we should expect: A demand for immediate political intervention to stop communism from happening.

Nobody in their right mind wants communism because it naturally emerges in the form of a huge social catastrophe. It is like the B.B. King saying, “Everybody wants to go to heaven but no one wants to die to get there.” Everybody wants to live without the need to sell their labor power and the daily grind of wage labor, but nobody wants to be unemployed.

However, so far as I know, with the exception of a few old patriarchs, everyone who went to heaven had to die first. So it would appear that we are destined to fight against the emergence of communism until all means of fighting are exhausted. Thus fight is a profound political reaction to the terrifying prospect of unemployment and operates on a level of consciousness that is not easily combated. The reaction of the entire society, and of both classes in society, is to prevent the emergence of communism at all costs.

This political reaction, however, operates on two distinct levels that should not be conflated. We need to deconstruct the fear communism inspires in the working class.

Deconstructing fear

If we go back to volume 1 of Capital, Marx begins his analysis of the capitalistic mode of production by distinguishing  between the two aspects of the commodity: exchange value and use value. I believe the reaction of the two classes is each related to a different aspect of this initial contradiction.

Although the political reaction of both classes is the same, each class expresses in its politics a fear regarding the impact on their material conditions of existence of different aspects of commodity production. With regards to the capitalist class, the reaction is tied to the commodity as an exchange value; however, with regards to the working class, its reaction is tied to the commodity as a use value.

Which is to say, the capitalists experience the end of wage labor as the end of the production of value and surplus value; while the working class experiences the end of wage labor as an actual mortal threat to its physical existence, as the threat of starvation.

The distinction between the two classes here must be emphasized because the end of wage labor may indeed be the end of commodity production, but this does not imply the end of both value and use value production. While value production comes to an end, the production of use values does not and cannot come to an end.

And this distinction is also critical to our consideration because the production of use values does not in any way necessarily depend on living labor. Use values can be produced in huge quantities with only a negligible quantity of living labor incorporated into their production.

At the political level of the social reaction to the idea of 100% unemployment, both classes have the same reaction: They will both fight against the emergence of communism with all means at their disposal. This implies that, at the level of politics, communists of all varieties will never be anything but a marginal political force. To the extent communists aim at the end of wage labor, this aim cannot have anything more than a marginal political expression. Communism can only be the aim of society to the extent the production of use values can be separated from the production of exchange value.

Theoretically the separation of the production of use values from the production of exchange values can only begin once the productive activity of the working class is not solely engaged in production of exchange value. This requires society has free disposable time to engage in productive activities that do not and cannot in any way aim at producing exchange values.

In other words, the separation of production of use values from exchange values is possible only when free disposable time of society becomes the prime source of use values. I think this cannot happen until almost all (or at least the largest part) of the personal time of individuals in society is free disposable time. The larger the quantity of free disposable time society possesses, the more likely this free time will itself become the most important source of material wealth.

The problem we face at present is that the production of material wealth cannot be separated from the production of value, because the working class has very little time of its own to engage in any activity that is not premised on value production. This cannot be fixed by demanding the state create jobs, handout basic income, raise the minimum wage or other measures very popular on the Left right now. It cannot even be fixed by more advanced ideas like market socialism, cooperatives and even Soviet style central planning.

The problem is not how wage labor is organized, managed or compensated; it is how communists propose to abolish it in a way that does not result in a catastrophe.

16 thoughts on ““Everybody wants to go to heaven, but no one wants to die to get there””

  1. “Use values can be produced in huge quantities with only a negligible quantity of living labor incorporated into their production.” what do you mean by “living labor” and that only a negligible amount is needed? thanks.

    Like

      1. Ever been in a cabinet shop?

        Or a machine shop?

        Or an auto assembly line?

        Or a meat packing plant?

        Or, my second home, a construction site?

        Material production is a lot more labor intensive than you think it is, brother (trust me on that, I’ve been an industrial proletarian since 1988 – I’ve lived the reality you pretend doesn’t exist because it doesn’t fit your theory)

        Like

      2. Add all of those forms of labor together in term of total percentage of American employment. How much is it. Now throw in all the material production of the entire defense industry. Does it change much?

        These forms of labor have been declining in relative and absolute numbers since 1979. Labor is dead and nothing will bring it back.

        Like

  2. You say:

    “…the end of wage labor may indeed be the end of commodity production, but this does not imply the end of both value and use value production. While value production comes to an end, the production of use values does not and cannot come to an end.
    …the production of use values does not in any way necessarily depend on living labor. Use values can be produced in huge quantities with only a negligible quantity of living labor incorporated into their production.”

    Here, I think, is a problem we, the communists, must adress. You talk about the quantity of use values, but… Are the use values in a communist society the same use values at the present time, simply without the exchange value aspect? Or are they of a different kind? Put in another way: Is the labour that produce use values in a communist society the same as in the present society, or is it of a different kind?
    I think they are not the same.
    Use values, and the labour that produces them, are formatted to fit in a capitalist social form. Without this form they must assume another form as use values: some use values will not be produce anymore, some new will emerge as neccesary, some will change completely their characteristics. And, more important, the labour that produces them must also change, and in a radical way. In short, the different use values and their different labours wil recover their characteristics, the will become more concrete and will become non equivalents.
    Another related question. Is the centralization of the means of production in their capitalist form the only way they can be centralized. Will it be neccesary to centralize everything, as in the present, or the change in the use values and in the concrete labour will require a different kind? Will not be neccesary to decentralize some branches to make them fit our communists purposes? And what kind of machines will we require.
    A communist association will need a completly different way of relating itself with nature, and a differente concept of nature. Not this mass of abstract substance we are accustomed to handle.

    Put in the context of your post. You correctly point that “The problem is not how wage labor is organized, managed or compensated; it is how communists propose to abolish it in a way that does not result in a catastrophe.” I agree that market socialism, cooperatives and even Soviet style central planning.are not the answer. And they are not precisely because these are forms of socializing abstract labour, not of abolishing it.

    Like

    1. This is some good stuff. I hope you write it up. I am very intrigued by it. Kurz raised many of the same question you do in a paper he published on the subject.

      Like

  3. More in this line. In “Private property and communism” (Manuscripts of 1844), after saying that possesing is not the opposite of private property, Marx goes on and say:

    “Private property has made us so stupid and one-sided that an
    object is only ours when we have it—when it exists for us as
    capital [so, private property], or when it is directly possessed, eaten, drunk, worn, inhabited, etc.,—in short, when it is used by us.”
    “In the place of all physical and mental senses there has
    therefore come the sheer estrangement of all these senses, the
    sense of having. The human being had to be reduced to this
    absolute poverty in order that he might yield his inner wealth to
    the outer world.”

    And in a footnote he writes: “In practice I can relate myself to a thing humanly only if the thing relates itself humanly to the human being.”

    So, communism implies that things must loose their character as use values.

    Like

    1. Wow. I am impressed by your line of thought on this. Please write it up and publish it somewhere. I would love to read it. I nevrr really thought about use value and its transformation under communism before now excpet in the most limited way.

      Like

  4. This article is right about one thing:

    “If you ever want to make a good case against communism to a worker, tell her that communists want the following things:

    Everyone is unemployed
    No one has any income
    Democracy no longer exists
    No one can own anything”

    That sounds like slavery – my great grandparents gave that lifestyle a try..by all accounts, it really really really sucked

    Who the hell would want to live under a system like that?

    If that’s this argument for communism, I’m ready to be pro capitalist (and I’ve been a communist since I was 14)!

    My communism involves pretty much the 180 degree opposite of that

    – everybody is employed

    – everybody has a decent income (no billionaires and no beggars)

    – democracy is at a far higher level than it could ever be under capitalism

    – everybody has the goods they need for a decent comfortable life

    That joke meme “Yacht Communism”?

    That’s what I want – Lenin called it “universal prosperity instead of universal poverty” and it’s what I’ve dedicated my life to fighting for

    As for what this person is advocating?

    It’s a 1950’s era Voice of America parody of everything the rulers say is bad about communism and, indeed, no worker would ever support this new jack slavery.

    So yeah, thanks no thanks for this Laverenti Beria-ish slave “communism”

    Like

Leave a comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.