Six points on Kontra Klasa’s “Notes on the Transition”

I have been reading this interesting piece by Kontra Klasa, Notes on the transition to communism. The essay, reprinted in the July 2018 issue of INTRANSIGENCE, tries to update communist strategy to meet the conditions of the 21st century. I thought it had some ideas worth considering, so I will highlight them here in a short note.

There has also been a reply to this piece which I am in the process of reading. I will post some notes on that reply at a later time.

*****

1.

This piece begins with the assertion that little has been added of substance to what has already been written on the transition between capitalism and communism by classical communists prior to World War II:

“Communist treatments of the transition between capitalist society and communism are not as numerous as one might perhaps imagine. Despite the importance of the subject, it seems many theoreticians are content to repeat or elaborate on the scarce few lines that Marx or Lenin have devoted to the subject. … And often, those treatments that exist are quite unconvincing. First of all, because many of them involve a very “thin” conception of communism (or socialism), as in the famous Leninist dictum that socialism is state capitalism made to serve the entire people. (Of course, we are never told how capitalism, of any sort, can serve “the people,” and who “the people” might be.)”

The assertion, although startling, is important. The conception of the transition from capitalism to communism offered by most communists has changed little since the days of classical communism.

2.

What then is Kontra Klasa’s conception of the transition from capitalism to communism in the 21st century? Burying their lede well down in paragraph ten of the essay for some strange reason, Kontra Klasa offer this statement:

“Members of the society in transition will have access to goods regardless whether or how much they labor …. there is no need to further develop the productive forces, at least in the metropolitan regions where revolution will most likely to break out. For the principle of distribution, we see nothing else as adequate except the classic ‘to each according to his needs.’”

In other words, as Kontra Klasa sees things in the 21st century, a fully developed communist society — one in which all the basic needs of the members of society can be met with only voluntary labor — is possible right now, at least in the most developed regions of the world market. To be sure, such a society will not be able to meet every fanciful whim of every member of society, but all basic needs, (which might be defined in terms of a basket of basic goods), can be met without requiring labor of anyone as their basic right as member of the commune.

Thus Kontra Klasa adds its name to a growing list of communists who believe there is no reason for a long period of transition between capitalism and communism. Capitalist development has laid the material foundation for a fully developed communist society from day one of the revolution. The long period of transition between capitalism and communism, so long held to be a fundamental precept of communist strategy, is at last being widely challenged.

3.

This new strategy allows us to avoid many of the pitfalls that arise from the previous one, which was based on the progressive encroachment of proletarian communal power over the forces of production as envisioned in the Communist Manifesto and the strategies proposed by the Second and Third Internationals:

“The classical expression of this is the belief that statification of the capitalist economy is equal to movement toward communism, and that in the communist society instruments remarkably similar to money — whether called labor notes, certificates, or something else is irrelevant — will operate.

“Modern capitalism, however, is unlike prior modes of production in that it comprises a total system: i.e., a whole whose general character and laws of motion imbue every part with nothing accidental or extraneous. From wage labor to parliamentary politics, every aspect of capitalist society is capitalist, and remains such when it is translated into an ambiguous situation. This, as well as the immense pressures of near-universal support for capitalism and the sheer social inertia acting in its favor, means that any ambiguous or transitional situation will eventually be resolved in a capitalist manner. One might without much exaggeration question if it is possible to exit a total system…”

Thus, according to Kontra Klasa, the 1848 strategy advocated in the Communist Manifesto appears to be obsolete, as does the strategy of the Social Democrats and the Leninists.

4.

But, surprisingly, Kontra Klasa also appears to deny the possibility that capitalist accumulation can lead to its own self-negation:

“…(and let us note that collapse is not a possibility short of the extinction of the species; modes of production do not collapse into nothing, but rather are replaced by other arrangements of productive activity)”

In this parenthetical statement, and contrary to Marx, Kontra Klasa seems to conflate capitalism with the production of material wealth. This is a typical amateur’s mistake. Kontra Klasa should know that capitalism is not the production of material wealth; it is the production of surplus value, production for profit. Production of material wealth and production of profit are not the same thing. Production for profit is merely a relative, historical form of production of material wealth. This distinction always must be kept in mind. Contrary to Kontra Klasa, production for profit can indeed collapse without bringing about the extinction of the species.

5.

Since Kontra Klasa has ruled out all the usual paths to communism, it is not clear at this point exactly how Kontra Klasa’s commune comes into existence beyond a few cryptic statements:

“The only remaining hope for the species is thus that a consciously-inflicted, sufficiently severe and rapid blow struck against exchange society would be capable of doing just that.

And,

“But the aforementioned blow — the revolution or general insurrection against value and property — must then induce as complete a break as possible with capitalist forms of society.”

Of what this “insurrection” consists, and how it imposes a complete break with capitalism is left unsaid by the authors.

The term, insurrection, is itself ambiguous — perhaps deliberately so. What do they propose concretely? This idea has to be fleshed out.

The insurrection is held to be a conscious act. It is rapid, aimed against exchange, value and property and is said to constitute a complete break with capitalist forms. According to Kontra Klasa, it would immediately realize a society founded on the principle of “to each according to need.”

The insurrection immediately puts an end to capitalist society. In the previous section, however, Kontra Klasa told us that this must lead to extinction of the species. Capitalism can’t just be replaced by nothing. (Or does this only apply to a collapse, but not to an insurrection?)

We can only conclude that this insurrection differs from all previous insurrections by immediately replacing capitalism with itself.

In the 21st Century, the insurrection itself is communism!

Kontra Klasa has led us to this unambiguous conclusion. Now let’s see them explain their results.

6.

Moreover, it appears Kontra Klasa believes that this communism, however constituted, will still be economically insufficient, at least initially. I am not sure why they think this must be true.

Of course, the communism will be dependent on commodities that are produced outside its zone of influence. Both the United States and Europe are dependent on many commodities they lack that are produced elsewhere within the world market. A communism emerging within either territory will be no less dependent.

But note here that, in the thinking of the authors, the communism is most likely to emerge in the most capitalistically developed regions of the world market. Fully developed communist relations will be possible immediately in the commune precisely because the communism will most likely emerge in the most capitalistically developed regions of the world market.

It doesn’t take a lot of intuition to realize that these more developed regions of the world market also serve as the markets for many of the commodities produced in the less developed regions of the world market — as the United States and Europe do for China.

But if the more developed regions of the world market suddenly withdraw from world trade bound up with capital, what then happens to the commodity production and exchange in the less developed regions? Won’t a revolution in the United States or Europe immediately push the less developed regions of the world market into a deep and prolonged crisis?

Imagine, for instance, how difficult it would be for China to fill an annual $506 billion hole, (2017 figure based on US Census Bureau data), in its economy if the US suddenly withdrew from the world market following a communist revolution.

Meanwhile, the commune in the United States would be putting an end to all compulsory labor and allocating basic consumer goods to its members based on need or on the basis of such a minimal requirement of necessary labor — five or six hours per week — that it amounts to this.

As China collapsed into a deep and prolonged crisis, the working class of the United States would emancipate itself from wage slavery. This would have to have a profound moral impact on social relations in China.

Kontra Klasa has not thought through the material economic implications of the emergence of a communism in the most capitalistically developed regions of the world market. Had they done so, it would have been obvious that most of their thinking on trade was based on irrelevant Soviet-era experience. They need to go back an re-examine many of their assumptions in this section.

15 thoughts on “Six points on Kontra Klasa’s “Notes on the Transition””

  1. I think you may have interpreted the parenthetical differently than the author(s) intended. They wrote:

    “…(and let us note that collapse is not a possibility short of the extinction of the species; modes of production do not collapse into nothing, but rather are replaced by other arrangements of productive activity)…”.

    In my interpretation, this reads more like a reference to the idea that “collapse” is a singular event that leads to a nightmarish post-apocalyptic world just “..short of the extinction of the species…”, when it should really be thought of as a transition to the next mode of production — hopefully one not based on profit.

    If you remove the parenthetical, it reads:

    “One might without much exaggeration question if it is possible to exit a total system. The only remaining hope for the species is thus that a consciously-inflicted, sufficiently severe and rapid blow struck against exchange society would be capable of doing just that.”

    The following paragraph explains what they believe will happen if there is no exit:

    “If this turns out not to be the case, the best human society can hope for is that some kind reformist might contrive to make euthanasia available on the cheap. For it is important to emphasize, against those who would have the revolution be a remote dream, that industrial society in its current form is nearing an end one way or another. Already it is impossible to stop anthropogenic climate change.”

    In other words, capitalism’s negation implies a point where an ecological threshold is reached that prevents it’s self-reproduction. If we consider the ongoing weather/climate extremes induced by global warming and extrapolate a few decades, assuming capitalism persists up to that threshold, the results appear catastrophic. Therefore, a socialist revolution must occur if humanity is to be saved.

    Unfortunately, without going into the nature of the revolution itself, they propose to essentially build a socialist capital that competes with other twenty-first century capitals. Why isn’t modern China the embodiment of that notion? There is no such thing as a capital that competes on the world market today that is consistent with ecological stability. All input chains depend on cheap energy, immense waste, and environmental destruction to fuel the grown necessary to remain a capital.

    Capitalism is a system that suppresses the mind’s propensity to deepen it’s understanding of nature, mankind’s relationship with it, and where it should go. Wage labor is a form of work devoted to mindlessness, but has the purpose to eliminate humans from existence by making them superfluous to themselves. It doesn’t matter what form this takes, socialist or not. Solutions that propose to copy the philosophical roots and capitalism, even accidentally, are deeply flawed.

    Leftists should focus on solutions that aren’t based on more work, but on how to withdraw from the labor market indefinitely. Expansion should take the form of absorbing the reserve army of labor.

    Like

    1. So, collapse? Yes? No? Or just the typical winding down into Mad Max? In other words, what happens when the profit rate falls to zero?
      1. Does production for profit halt or not?
      2. Does the production of material wealth come to an end along with production for profit?

      Liked by 1 person

      1. Yes.

        I believe this passage is alluding to some point where capitalist society will simply be unable to extract enough resources to meet even minimal growth (production for profit becomes impossible). That “threshold” is defined, and I’m clearly injecting my own thoughts, when the system is unable to supply cheap energy and food at the rate it requires. If things get that bad considering how much capitalism already squeezes out of the environment, then the state of nature in general must be so severe that euthanasia may need to become the new basis of production.

        Production on the basis of euthanasia.

        This may or may not be what they intend to convey.

        Like

      2. This is very similar to the prediction made by Ricardo, at least according to Marx. The crisis is attributed to natural barriers to accumulation. Marx discusses this in v3, ch15. I am not saying it is wrong. I am only saying it is not Marx prediction.

        Like

      3. I’m theorizing on the end of capitalism as an epoch rather than its periodic crises, which from our perspective in 2018, appears to be correlated with some point where resources required for material production will not be sufficient to start a new cycle. Specifically, a build-up environmental decay that disrupts the deployment of wage labor with great enough frequency and scope. So, in that way, I’m attributing the finale to natural barriers.

        I don’t think that’s inconsistent with Marx’s theories on capitalism’s tendencies and counter-tendencies. I’m not sure what Ricardo had to say regarding the end of capitalism.

        In chapter 15, Marx writes:

        “Two labourers, each working 12 hours daily, cannot produce the same mass of surplus-value as 24 who work only 2 hours, even if they could live on air and hence did not have to work for themselves at all. In this respect, then, the compensation of the reduced number of labourers by intensifying the degree of exploitation has certain insurmountable limits.”

        Natural limitations seem well integrated in Marx’s analysis, human related or not.

        Let’s say the capitalist keeps the degree of exploitation constant, yet, due to a prolonged drought, food becomes less available. This lowers the insurmountable limit even further than before. You can generalize this to say something like the average limit of exploitation decreases some amount per .1C rise in global average temperature. Eventually, I would think this prevents capital from expanding at all — collapse.

        Like

    2. I would read the parenthetical as saying that the capitalist mode will not spontaneously collapse under crisis but will. rather, upon each crisis, rapidly reconfigure itself — revolutionize itself while still retaining Marx’s essential categories (value, exchange, property, time, or so.).

      When a deep, deep crisis hits – maybe USSR or even Greece – people don’t “automatically” try something different. They pine and even show up to help the return of jobs, wages, capital in circulation, etc. Cooperation never arrives. The bourgeoisie soon enough gets the game moving again and the proletariat do everything they can to boost this effort.

      I would read the conscious effort as something like a critical-mass awareness of the non-necessity of wage relations sufficient to begin willfully violating them. Let me unpack that:

      I am not talking about a general strike where everyone steps away from their station and offers to fight the police and army.

      I am talking about something like a critical mass of sabotage of the circulation of capital with, in the same action, the deployment of survival strategies that keep essential production going, and that distribute on the basis of need.

      If I were to try to write fiction about what that looks like, maybe something like utility companies shutting off service to many entities, say, banks for an example — overnight conversion of grocery stores to food banks — a volunteer campaign to go lighten the burden of farm workers — etc.

      “Internationally”, maybe that would look like an outbreak of generosity from the new commune — sending whatever it could to areas of need, to be able to ask for a little help from exporters we depend on.

      There are hard barriers here that I think are very hard. For example, AFAICT (so take with a big grain of salt), subsistance ag requires things like the continued operation of big chemical plants, oil extraction, etc. The group of people who possess the knowledge to operate these facilities at all well is very small relative to general population and — through the educational and hiring system that got them there — are apt to be really, really, really, deep, very addicted commodity fetishists.

      Like

      1. Yes. Everyone pretty much agree production for profit cannot collapse, just as they believed production based on exchange value could not collapse. They will be as really fucking surprised as they were in the 1930s. Marx has never been proved wrong.

        Like

  2. From “Notes on the transition to communism” by Kontra Klasa => “In fact, apart from this production for sale, there is no reason why production and distribution should not, immediately, be organized so that a “SCIENTIFIC SOCIAL PLAN” based on human need regulates both.”

    From “Socialism: Utopian and Scientific” by Frederick Engels => “To thoroughly comprehend the historical conditions and this the very nature of this act, to impart to the now oppressed proletarian class a full knowledge of the conditions and of the meaning of the momentous act it is called upon to accomplish, this is the task of the theoretical expression of the proletarian movement, “SCIENTIFIC SOCIALISM”.”

    I think you identified the key area that needs to be explored with regards to a transition to communism here => “Production of material wealth and production of profit are not the same thing. Production for profit is merely a relative, historical form of production of material wealth.”

    Production of material wealth is now almost entirely rooted in the socilaization of labour, I can’t imagine any reason to abandon that. Any theory of transition must be centered on the production of material wealth sans wages.

    Like

  3. I want to challenge claims that:

    a) A bad enough internal crisis of capital can be sufficient in and of itself to end capitalist social relations.

    b) External constraints – particularly ecological ones – are enough to guarantee an end to capitalism.

    Idea (a) suggests we communists just bide our time. Capitalism will fall. And then we can all chat about how to move. Or something.

    Chapter 15 v3, common sense, and empirical history show that capitalist crises are mainly personal crises only for the proletariat. During a crisis the proletariat is suffering the breakdowns in the circulation of capital and is in its *worst* position stride forward into new, non-capitalist social relations.
    For capitalists and capital, on the other hand, crises are perpetually reinvigorating and renewing because they prompt reconfiguration of capital flows to adapt to accumulated developments of the mode. Crises are not the friend of communists or the direct precursor to communism.

    Idea (b) imagines that capitalists are idiots who will create resource shortages without, on the way, also planning for them. Idea (b) imagines that capitalists are not capable of genocide, that they are not capable of managing a mass population, that they do not have any clue how to protect their own position in the face of scarcity. Why would anyone believe (b)?

    Like

    1. In defense of “b”:

      The ecological crisis points toward the collapse of civilization, which is capitalist in general. What form it takes after its capitalist character becomes untenable is left to speculation. The main point is that without a revolution, or transition in some form, there really is no other outcome from an ecological standpoint. The futurist or accelerationist perspective, from what I understand, where capitalism develops the technology sophisticated enough to overcome insurmountable limits set by nature, is entirely baseless and antithetical to capital’s propensity to eschew sustainable technologies/social arrangements in favor of those supportive of profit and growth — a dynamic which has repeated itself since the industrial revolution and has, from a geological perspective, already resulted in environmental collapse (www.pnas.org/content/pnas/114/30/E6089.full.pdf).

      In respect to individual capitalists, I’d say on average the market-based paradigm prevails when dealing with resource shortages i.e, demand will shift to other industries, alternative resources will be found, profit will be made by whoever benefits and the system will tend to equalize over time. If there is any proactive effort into dealing with perceived shortages, it’s to figure out how to profit from increased demand in some way. If there is some kind of technological advancement that increases efficiency, it only runs into, under the capitalist mode of production, Jevon’s paradox. I certainly buy the idea that any individual or group of capitalists will go to any length to protect their assets, but if pressure to protect their position comes from a state of widespread scarcity then that implies the breakdown in circuit of capital, which I don’t think would be recoverable if we’re talking about that event in the context of the global ecological crisis.

      Like

      1. This premise has a problem: “The ecological crisis points toward the collapse of civilization, …. What form it takes after its capitalist character becomes untenable ….”

        Let’s take the model that says ecological footprint per geographic area is the (P * A * T) / C: people times relative affluence times average ecological intensity of output divided by average carrying capacity of an area that size.

        In that case, ecological footprint of any “controlled” geographic area can be reduced by raising the global average efficiency of production (but this is sharply limited) —- or, more practically, by reducing the affluence and/or number of people in that geographic region.

        Mass incarceration and various forms of controlled genocide suggest themselves as viable strategies for rapidly mediating the causes of climate climate change, perhaps even creating a base supply of very cheap labor that can be spent on activities to begin to reverse climate change.

        In a lower stage of capitalist development, these strategies would have been unlikely. For one: that would tend to harm the supply of a formerly scarce resource (labor power) — labor power had more productive uses. Two: the economic activity of carbon remediation (say, planting and burying crops) would have been unproductive in a capitalist society — the output could not have been realized as expanded capital.

        Yet, in modern capitalism: For one: there is no scarcity of labor power, genocide is fine for the capitalist. For two: Labor is increasingly superfluous and the monetary regime of a fiat currency allows capital to grow by spending ever greater amounts of labor on superfluous (that is to say, unrealizable) capital output.

        I wonder if this de-personalization of humans isn’t what Nick Land is talking about (see an earlier, recent post on this blog).

        Anyway, what I have described surely is “collapse of civilization” — but mainly from the standpoint of the proletariat. Capitalism continues in this scenario, from the standpoint of a bourgeoisie who constitute the state.

        Like

      2. Well, capitalism persists despite the feelings of the proletariat. What I believe your scenario describes is one where capitalist civilization is saved from its current fate by reducing affluence (by population reduction) while simultaneously restoring the environment to a state agreeable with capital expansion. As far as the method of population reduction is concerned and what Nick Land thinks about it, I’m not entirely sure. I think the idea that profit-driven forces of capitalism can be exploited beneficially is misguided, proved false by the state of the climate today. The more interesting question is can capitalist civilization go through some kind of a “downgrade” necessary to continue its reproduction by way of depopulation “management”. I don’t think so.

        A managed depopulation scenario would have to address a timescale problem first. It would have to rapidly reduce the population at a rate faster than the rate the climate is changing to its warmer state (it’s currently undergoing a state change from a colder to warmer state, driven purely by inertia), and to some level below even the 19th century level to account for the depleted resources since the industrial revolution. The necessary level would have to be low enough to allow for capital to expand again within the relatively poorer ecological environment, and because this is a managed scenario, it’s assumed they figure out a way to do this without immediately regressing into another crisis through good planning and technology. This already sounds pretty far-fetched, but it runs into a problem when you consider there will be a second, third, forth, etc. time to undergo the exact same process under consecutively worse environments.

        There’s another problem that is more conceptually difficult in my view. A managed scenario implies an agreement among capitalists over who wins/loses from the decreased demand, killed off capital. At this point, competition is suspended temporarily in order to restore it later. If that becomes possible, why restore capitalism at all? If they know the capitalist mode of production lead to its suspension, it would, in theory, make more sense to continue with the post-capitalist regime. That might actually describe the prophetic moment where capitalism self-negates for good.

        I think it’s easier to analyze the current trends in a classical Marxist sense, assume we’ll see another crisis, recovery through peace or war, another tepid expansion where workers become worse off, and extreme weather events become so frequent and intense they will penetrate all segments of society to the point where capitalism will not even be considered a serious topic of discussion.

        Like

Leave a comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.